Phase transitions and AGI

Link post

Take a look at the following graph, from Robin Hanson’s Long-Term Growth As a Sequence of Exponential Modes:

graph

Here, “world product” is roughly the gross world product divided by the level of income necessary for one person to live at a subsistence level. It measures the total production of the human species in units of “how many people could live at a subsistence level on that much production?”

The yellow marks are historical estimates of world product that Hanson gathered from a variety of sources, and he’s fit three different models to this data. What’s notable is the good fit that the “sum of exponentials” type models have with this data. It looks like the world economy goes through different phases which are characterized by different rates of growth: in the first phase world product doubled every years, in the second phase it doubled every years, and in the third phase it doubled every years, where we can give or take a factor of from these estimates—they are meant only to convey the order of magnitude differences.

We also see that transitions to subsequent phases are relatively fast. The transition from the first phase to the second phase took years, much less than the doubling time of years characterizing this phase, and the transition from the second phase to the third took on the order of years, still smaller than the years of doubling time typical of the second phase. We can also observe that the timing of these events roughly matches the First Agricultural Revolution and the Industrial Revolution, so we might tentatively label the phases as corresponding to “foraging”, “farming” and “industry” respectively.

The study of these past transitions is important because they are the only reference class we have for dramatic changes in the nature of the world economy and in how the human species is organized and how we coordinate our activities. Since we have two transitions to examine, we might also get a rudimentary sense of the variance of outcomes: two is the minimal value we need in order to do that.

Unfortunately, many details about the foraging phase are shrouded in mystery. There’s still no consensus on the world product estimates for this phase even today: it could be that this phase was actually ten times shorter than we think it is, and it might only date back to around 200,000 BCE rather than 2,000,000 BCE. In this case, the doubling time in this phase would be higher, about years. This is still much slower than what came after, and still large compared to how long it took for the transition to take place.

Regardless, the first conclusion we should draw from this reference class is that such phase transitions are possible and they can happen surprisingly quickly compared to the pace of the changes that people who lived in a particular phase would be used to. We can draw a second conclusion by noting that while the durations of the phases vary quite a lot, the number of doublings of world product in each phase seems to be similar: , give or take a factor of . Given the small sample size and the difficulties of generalization, it’s hard to extrapolate the duration of the industrial phase based on this information, but it does suggest that the phase coming to an end soon wouldn’t be surprising from an outside point of view.

The question this essay is meant to answer is broadly this: how likely is a phase transition in the near future, and given that one occurs, how likely is it to be brought about by AGI? (By definition, I take transformative AI to be precisely a development in AI which triggers such a phase transition.)

Outside view

One important question we should ask is how far in advance it’s possible to see phase transitions coming. The answer to this seems to be “less than half of a doubling time” given the past examples. In other words, since the world economy is currently doubling every 20 years or so, we probably shouldn’t expect to see any sign of an impending phase transition until we’re less than a decade away from it. Therefore, the fact that nothing special seems to be happening now shouldn’t affect our assessment of the odds of a phase transition in the next century.

On the other hand, the outside view also should lead us to be cautious about what mode of organization will become dominant after the phase transition. It would have been quite difficult to anticipate in the year 1400 that the next phase would be associated with industry, since industry wasn’t growing particularly fast relative to anything else in 1400.

Can we get a more precise idea about how long we can expect the industrial phase to last from an outside point of view? Here is one way to go about doing this: assume that where is the number of doublings in a phase is drawn from a Pareto distribution with an unknown tail exponent . Pareto distributions have heavy right tails and allow for a lot of uncertainty. This means the forecasts it implies will be quite conservative on transformative AI timelines, which might be a disadvantage for reasons I’ll come back to shortly.

A Pareto distribution has one parameter: the exponent . If we had a lot of data then we could estimate using frequentist methods (such as maximum likelihood estimation) but since we don’t, we have to use Bayesian methods to get anything useful out of this analysis.

The conjugate prior of the Pareto distribution is the same as the one of the exponential distribution, since the logarithm of a Pareto distributed random variable is exponentially distributed. This conjugate prior is given by the gamma distribution.

We start with the Jeffreys prior for the Pareto distribution, which is simply an improper prior proportional to . This formally corresponds to a gamma distribution where the distribution is characterized in terms of its shape and rate respectively. Now, we do a Bayesian update: we have two observations of past phases and they took approximately 8.9 and 7.5 doublings—these values are taken from Hanson’s paper—for the foraging and farming phases respectively. Using the conjugate prior updating rule for the exponential distribution after adding 1 and taking logarithms, we update to the posterior distribution

Now we can do a Monte Carlo simulation by first sampling values of from the posterior and conditioning on there having been at least 10 doublings so far in the current phase, and then sampling some value of the number of doublings until the end of the current phase. This give us a sample from which we can infer what the percentiles of various outcomes must be.

The cumulative distribution function looks like this:

pareto_cdf

The reason the percentiles after the median get so large is because of the aforementioned property that the Pareto distribution has heavy tails. Since sustaining doublings indefinitely has a substantial chance of being outside the realm of physical possibilities, we might want to also try using a distribution which has thinner tails. A natural choice for this is the exponential distribution.

This calculation is remarkably similar since the exponential and Pareto distributions are closely related. Now we assume the number of doublings is drawn directly from an exponential distribution with an unknown rate parameter . Once again the Jeffreys prior for is , and a similar Bayesian update gets us the posterior

Repeating the Monte Carlo simulation from before in this new context gives the following cumulative distribution function:

expon_cdf

Which of these is a better choice? In my judgment the exponential distribution in this case is giving much more realistic timelines, and it’s what I will be primarily relying on in order to make my forecasts. I include both models, however, as a way to show that our choice of model really affects our view of what the timeline should be like.

The main argument against using heavy tailed priors is that the number of doublings is already the base two logarithm of the factor by which world product increases by in a phase, so if we assume a heavy tailed distribution for it then we have to exponentiate that in order to get the actual growth in world product. This becomes similar to a double exponential which has a high probability of exceeding physical limits—how confident are we that, say, 9000 doublings of world product is even physically possible at all, let alone it all occurring in a single phase?

I also experimented with using a model in which is sampled from a gamma distribution, but because its Jeffreys prior doesn’t belong to its family of conjugate priors Bayesian inference on it gets quite hairy. In the end the results I get are somewhat more pessimistic than using an exponential, but the difference isn’t pronounced.

Inside view

I think conditional on there being a phase transition in the next hundred years or so, it’s likely (around 65%) that the cause of the transition will be the development of transformative AI. However, even if this is not true, reverse causality will then become operative: it’s very hard to imagine that AGI is not achieved a short time after a phase transition. Even a factor 10 increase in the growth rate of the economy would be enough for AGI timelines to become quite compressed, for instance.

The reason I would give 65% odds to AGI being the driver of such a phase transition is that it’s hard for me to tell a plausible story about any other technology that’s currently on the horizon doing so. Moreover, one of the signs of a part of the economy that will be responsible for a phase transition is that it should have a fast growth rate and a plausible mechanism by which that fast growth rate can be sustained and take over the whole economy, and I think the only serious contender for this position right now is AI research. I wouldn’t go higher than 65% because a technology that we can’t yet see could end up being responsible for the phase transition: this is the same as the point I raised earlier about how industry wasn’t growing fast relative to the rest of the economy in 1400.

My opinion is that the inside view right now favors a phase transition sometime between 2 and 5 doublings. It’s difficult to imagine transformative AI coming along without at least one further doubling. Some relevant milestones here come from Holden Karnofsky’s post on transformative AI forecasting using biological anchors:

graph_2

As Karnofsky says in his post:

Bio Anchors estimates a >10% chance of transformative AI by 2036, a 50% chance by 2055, and an 80% chance by 2100.

I think this is extremely optimistic. I agree with the timeline in likelihood terms: the maximum likelihood estimate on when we get transformative AI is probably “two to five doublings”, which is roughly the same timeline here—again, their timeline seems a bit more optimistic, but broadly consistent. This roughly means that I think we would be most likely to be seeing the kind of world we are seeing now if we were around two to five doublings away from a phase transition.

However, a good Bayesian has to combine likelihoods with priors in order to get a posterior distribution, and this is my primary point of disagreement with the Bio Anchors timeline: the outside view, in other words the prior distribution, suggests a phase transition occuring soon is unlikely. The industrial phase is roughly 200 years old, and it has lasted for around 10 doublings already. Conditional on that, even if we just assume a constant rate of arrival for the end of the current phase (which will be rather optimistic), we should get a maximum likelihood estimate of around 10% every doubling for it to happen. The median forecast would then be around 7 doublings until the end of the current phase. If we want to go down from 7 to below 2, we need to have very strong evidence that a phase transition is going to happen, and I don’t think AI developments so far provide any such evidence.

More explicitly, consider the second cumulative distribution funciton plot above. Two doublings is roughly the 14th percentile of outcomes, so . The corresponding odds ratio is or so. To update from this odds ratio to even odds requires a Bayes factor of roughly . In other words, to justify a median forecast of two more doublings, the world would have to be 6 times more likely to look as it does under the hypothesis than under the alternative . In my judgment the available evidence comes nowhere close to meeting this stringent standard, and I’m curious to hear from people who think otherwise.

Most of the expectation of imminent transformative AI rests on extrapolations such as the one in the graph: if we train a big enough model (human brain-sized, or more accurately, of a similar inferential complexity to the human brain) for a long enough time (compute used by all of evolution), we’ll not only get human or superhuman performance on difficult tasks, but this performance will directly translate into a transformation of the global economy. I think the model uncertainty here is so large that updating too strongly away from the prior on this kind of argument is a bad idea.

Forecasts

There are three related questions that I’ll forecast on: GWP growth to exceed 6%, GWP growth to exceed 10% and When will economic growth accelerate? You can find the cumulative distribution function of my forecasts over at the linked post on Metaculus.

I think all three of these questions are unlikely to resolve if there is no phase transition: I think the first one has around 15% chance of not resolving > in the absence of one, while the second and third are 1% or less. Therefore, my forecasts on all three questions are based on taking my outside view estimates, adjusting them slightly upwards due to the arguments given in the inside view section, and then making further adjustments based on the specific question.

I think mean GWP growth exceeding 10% per year for a sufficiently long time is approximately equivalent to there being a phase transition—it’s highly unlikely that any phase transition would have a doubling time factor over the current phase that’s less than 3. However, 30% growth in a single year is a stronger demand, so I’ve adjusted the distribution downwards to account for that. You shouldn’t take the exact distribution too seriously, since it’s difficult to input exact distributions and I haven’t taken the effort to do so, but I’ve made sure that everything is consistent.

Mean GWP growth exceeding 6% could happen without a phase transition, but it’s rather unlikely. It would require major governments around the world enacting wide-reaching economic reforms, or an unprecedented economic boom across most of the underdeveloped world. I put the odds of this at around 15%, and my forecast is more or less a combination of this with my estimate of the arrival time of a phase transition.

Discussion

Most transformative AI timelines focus strongly on the inside view: how long until neural networks become as big as the human brain, how long until we reach certain compute thresholds, how long do researchers in the field think we have until transformative AI, et cetera. I think the inside view is useful, but in the process the outside view is either ignored or not weighted strongly enough to balance out inside considerations.

This essay is meant to be a corrective for that: using Bayesian methods it’s actually possible to get information about the timeline of when we can expect another phase transition purely based on the past two examples of such transitions. The distributions we get this way do end up being somewhat sensitive to assumptions about priors, especially at the tails, but overall I think using any standard “uninformative” prior is superior to just saying there’s no outside view on the problem and focusing only on the inside view.

Addendum: Someone over at Metaculus linked Semi-informative priors over AI timelines by Tom Davidson in the comments, which has a similar flavor to what I do here and ends up with similar timelines for a phase transition & transformative AI as I do. If you’re interested in this outside view perspective, his article is also worth reading.